Welcome to DU! The truly grassroots left-of-center political community where regular people, not algorithms, drive the discussions and set the standards. Join the community: Create a free account Support DU (and get rid of ads!): Become a Star Member Latest Breaking News General Discussion The DU Lounge All Forums Issue Forums Culture Forums Alliance Forums Region Forums Support Forums Help & Search

Baobab

(4,667 posts)
Fri Apr 1, 2016, 10:17 AM Apr 2016

bernie appears to me to be wildly overestimating taxes needed to accomplish our goals, especially if

we stop getting involved with new wars. On single payer, it seems to me that we are ALREADY SPENDING MORE THAN ENOUGH TO GIVE THE WHOLE COUNTRY HIGH QUALITY FREE HEALTH CARE! We are just wasting so much the way we do it now, also delays in treatment make it all much more expensive when people finally do go. All in all, I think the estimates of huge bossts in the economy are right and likely will be underestimates-




Here is the link on health care- we are already paying more than enough.

Also, we spend literally half of every tax dollar on the military and defense in one way or another.

If that goes down we can increase everything else we need and not pay more. We already spend more on our military than every other country on the planet does with theirs, combined.


------

Health care-

See The Current and Projected Taxpayer Shares of US Health Costs
David U. Himmelstein, MD, and Steffie Woolhandler, MD, MPH


Abstract:

Objectives. We estimated taxpayers’ current and projected share of US health expenditures,
including government payments for public employees’ health benefits as well as tax subsidies to
private health spending.

Methods. We tabulated official Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services figures on direct
government spending for health programs and public employees’ health benefits for 2013, and
projected figures through 2024. We calculated the value of tax subsidies for private spending from
official federal budget documents and figures for state and local tax collections.

Results. Tax-funded health expenditures totaled $1.877 trillion in 2013 and are projected to increase
to $3.642 trillion in 2024. Government’s share of overall health spending was 64.3% of national
health expenditures in 2013 and will rise to 67.1% in 2024. Government health expenditures in the
United States account for a larger share of gross domestic product (11.2% in 2013) than do total
health expenditures in any other nation.

Conclusions. Contrary to public perceptions and official Centers for Medicare and Medicaid Services
estimates, government funds most health care in the United States. Appreciation of government’s
predominant role in health funding might encourage more appropriate and equitable targeting of
health expenditures.

Rest of paper

13 replies = new reply since forum marked as read
Highlight: NoneDon't highlight anything 5 newestHighlight 5 most recent replies
 

Human101948

(3,457 posts)
2. A simple solution would be to stop trying to prolong the end of life with heroic measures...
Fri Apr 1, 2016, 10:24 AM
Apr 2016
Last year, Medicare paid $50 billion just for doctor and hospital bills during the last two months of patients' lives - that's more than the budget of the Department of Homeland Security or the Department of Education.

And it has been estimated that 20 to 30 percent of these medical expenditures may have had no meaningful impact. Most of the bills are paid for by the federal government with few or no questions asked.

http://www.cbsnews.com/news/the-cost-of-dying/

The Medicare Hospice Benefit, which covers most hospice care, requires that two doctors verify a patient has less than six months to live. A 2007 Duke University study published in Social Science & Medicine found that hospice care in American reduces Medicare expenditures during the last year of life by an average of $2,309 per hospice patient. In 2012 an estimated 1.5 to 1.6 million patients received hospice services.

http://www.usnews.com/news/articles/2014/09/23/study-end-of-life-plans-are-rare-driving-up-costs-and-suffering

Baobab

(4,667 posts)
4. A better solution is to STOP TELLING DOCTORS WHAT TO DO
Fri Apr 1, 2016, 10:30 AM
Apr 2016


#1 if people go in to doctors when they get sick, end of life costs will fall because more people will be healthy until they die 'naturally" at an advanced age without long diseases.

To do this we also need to reduce the chemicals around us. Actually those chemicals are making a LOT of people sick, and its costing a lot.

Plastics and endocrine disruptors, flame retardants, its a big problem - Thats why a lot of people are getting cancers.

See Estimating Burden and Disease Costs of Exposure to Endocrine-Disrupting Chemicals in the European Union

http://press.endocrine.org/doi/pdf/10.1210/jc.2014-4324
 

Human101948

(3,457 posts)
3. 30 percent of all health spending in 2009—was wasted on unnecessary services and other issues
Fri Apr 1, 2016, 10:27 AM
Apr 2016
The routine use of 130 different medical screenings, tests and treatments are often unnecessary and should be scaled back, according to 25 medical specialty organizations. The medical societies jointly released lists of tests and therapies patients should question in their campaign, Choosing Wisely. The initiative of the American Board of Internal Medicine Foundation is aimed at reducing unnecessary interventions that waste money and can actually do more harm than good.
A 2012 report by the Institute of Medicine estimated that $750 billion—about 30 percent of all health spending in 2009—was wasted on unnecessary services and other issues, such as excessive administrative costs and fraud. Many of those unnecessary services appear on the new lists released in February from Choosing Wisely. An additional 90 medical services were added to the 40 items initially listed by the campaign in April 2012.

http://www.scientificamerican.com/article/medical-procedures-prove-unnecessary/

Baobab

(4,667 posts)
5. I have seen a great deal of this so called evidence but I have seen far more evidence that says the
Fri Apr 1, 2016, 10:39 AM
Apr 2016

exact opposite and Europeans have told me the same- Americans UNDERUTILIZE health care compared to other rich countries.

In other words, we get less care. We are no more sicker than them but we get less care and its often delivered too late. Its also too expensive but that cost is not because of wages paid to doctors or nurses, its because we waste so much on the insurance layer- Half- i think we basically at least double the cost of health care- Also drug prces here are rising at an astronomical rate- in the US- 300% since Obama took office on some Rx drugs- even generics - this has to stop.


Public Attitudes Toward Health Care Spending Aren’t The Problem; Prices Are

Jonathan Oberlander and
Joseph White

University of North Carolina–Chapel Hill

Jonathan Oberlander (oberland{at}med.unc.edu)


Next Section
Abstract

Does the United States spend more on medical care than other nations because Americans desire more medical care than other populations do and dislike constraints on health spending? We argue that the public is not the main barrier to successful cost control in the United States. The preoccupation with excessive demand as the cause of and rationing as the cure for U.S. health spending overlooks an alternative explanation for that spending: higher prices. There is evidence that price regulation can constrain spending and that the public will support that cost-control approach.

Regulating prices and lowering administrative costs are central to curbing cost growth—and the public agrees.

The united states is singularly unsuccessful in controlling medical care costs. Other nations spend much less on medical care while attaining universal coverage and better health outcomes. Many policy analysts agree that the American health care system does not generate sufficient value for the extra money it spends relative to peer countries.1–3 Moreover, rising costs erode Americans’ access to health insurance, reduce workers’ wages, and strain federal and state budgets.

Why, then, has the United States not adopted effective cost controls? One possible explanation is that Americans actually have the health care system they want. In this view, U.S. spending on medical care is higher than in other nations because the American public desires more medical care and dislikes health spending constraints. As Washington Post columnist Robert Samuelson summarizes, “We have a health-care system that reflects our national values. It’s highly individualistic, entrepreneurial, and suspicious of centralized supervision. In practice, Medicare and private insurers impose few effective controls on doctors’ and patients’ choices. That’s the way most Americans want it.”4

Peter Neumann similarly stresses cultural explanations for the limited use of cost-effectiveness analysis (CEA) in U.S. health policy. He concludes that “at its roots, resistance to CEA in the United States is grounded, not in methodological or legal barriers, but in Americans’ penchant for medical innovation and our distaste for limits—and in our deep-rooted suspicion of governments or corporations that impose them.”5 Henry Aaron and William Schwartz famously argued that to control spending, the United States had to confront those limits and take a “painful prescription.” That meant adopting policies to explicitly ration potentially beneficial medical services.6

Health economics provides another explanation for Americans’ ostensibly unlimited taste for medical care: insurance creates “moral hazard,” which leads to overuse of medical services.7 In this view, American workers, shielded by the tax exclusion for employer-based health insurance, seek lavish “Cadillac coverage.”8 The implication is that excessive use drives the high costs of care.

Can the United States adopt meaningful measures to slow health care spending, given Americans’ supposed resistance to limits? We argue here that the public is not the main obstacle to successful cost control. The preoccupation with excessive demand as the cause of and rationing as the cure for U.S. health care spending leads health policy analysts to overlook an alternative explanation for that spending: higher prices. There is, in fact, evidence both that controlling price levels can constrain spending and that the public supports such constraints.

The remainder of the article proceeds as follows. We first review public opinion data and critically examine claims that Americans’ cultural preferences for more medical care explain the high level of U.S. spending. We then address the roles of prices and rationing in cost control. Finally, we analyze the political barriers to cost control and implications for the current health reform debate.
Previous SectionNext Section
The Public And Cost Control

The argument that the United States spends more on medical care than other countries because Americans want more medical care and less control is problematic in two key respects.
Relationship with use of services.

Despite our higher spending, for a broad scope of services Americans actually receive less medical care than citizens of other rich democracies. “Lower utilization,” as Bruce Vladeck has written, “doesn’t always equate to lower costs.”9
Use of services and prescription drugs.

Other nations in the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development (OECD) have, on average, more hospital beds and physicians than the United States has. The United States does have a comparatively high level of imaging units and inpatient surgeries. Yet patients in OECD countries average more hospital days, more physician visits, and greater consumption of prescription drugs than American patients do. Higher U.S. spending is not primarily explained by greater volume of services.10
Attitudes toward rationing.

If we are inferring cultural predispositions from utilization data, then we have as much reason to ask why Americans are more comfortable with rationing of hospital days and physician visits as we do to assert that Canadians and Europeans are more comfortable with rationing of high-technology services. And if Americans object so much to limits on medical care, those objections are not very effective. American insurance plans commonly have benefit limitations, restrictions on provider choice, and cost-sharing requirements that would be immensely controversial in other nations.
Out-of-pocket spending and coverage.

Indeed, out-of-pocket spending in the United States is roughly twice the OECD median.2 If some Americans have “Cadillac coverage,” then most workers in Germany or France must have “Mercedes coverage”—and they would likely view many American insurance policies as “Yugo coverage.” Yet Germany and France and all other countries spend much less on medical care than the United States does.2,10–13

We consequently cannot infer from high U.S. health spending that Americans want more medical care and more comprehensive insurance than citizens of other countries want. American insurers are, by international standards, generous in their payments to medical care providers. That should not, however, be confused with generous insurance coverage.
Attitudes toward cost control.

There is a second problem with the argument that U.S. health spending is high because the public won’t abide cost control. Public opinion data suggest that Americans favor some types of cost control. “Polls have long shown,” Drew Altman notes, “that the American people support regulatory action in health.”14 Even during the Reagan administration, write Mark Schlesinger and Taeku Lee, “the vast majority of Americans favored increasing government regulation of both the prices and the delivery of health services.”15 Seventy-seven percent of Americans polled in a 1984 survey supported “government price controls and regulations on what hospitals and doctors can charge.”16

These results persist today, according to a 2009 Kaiser Family Foundation/Harvard School of Public Health poll. Large percentages of Americans favor federal regulatory limits on health insurance companies’ profits (62 percent) and administrative expenses (65 percent), as well as requiring insurers to cover all applicants regardless of health status (78 percent).17 There is also strong public support for increasing government regulation of prescription drug prices (52 percent of respondents said that there was not enough of such regulation, compared with 23 percent who said that there was too much).17 Sixty-two percent of respondents in a 2006 survey believed that government regulation would be an effective strategy to control health care spending.18

To be sure, Americans register support for a variety of other cost-control strategies, including competition. The public is divided on the merits of different health reforms—just as experts are. Still, judging by these polls, Americans’ cultural aversion to regulating health care is overstated. Despite their contrasting health care systems, Americans do not differ much from Canadians in their views on the importance of access to advanced medical treatments. Nor do they differ much on the question of whether governments or other insurers can possibly pay for all new treatments. There are larger differences, however, between the United States and some European nations on these questions.19
Previous SectionNext Section
Limits Of Public Opinion

This does not mean that the public will endorse all forms of cost control. Public opinion is complex, divided, and at times contradictory.20,21 The public wants its costs controlled, for example, while in some surveys it favors more government spending on medical care.

There is also good evidence that many Americans oppose reform if it means reduced access to medical care. The public is eager for cost controls that limit their rising medical bills, not for restrictions on the availability of services. That makes any reform proposal vulnerable, as the Clinton administration discovered during 1993–94, to arguments that it will worsen access to care for insured people. Health reform plans are similarly susceptible to attacks on big government. Many Americans remain “suspicious of direct, massive government intervention.”20

Echoes of these earlier attacks can be heard in the current health reform debate. Some conservative activists and congressional Republicans argue that federally funded comparative effectiveness research could “ruin your health”22 and “lead to government rationing of health care.”23 Although many policy analysts object to those descriptions, public opinion experts view this as a winning line of attack on health reform precisely because it arouses the public’s suspicions.

As the Republican pollster Frank Luntz explains in a memo, the killer argument against reform is, “In countries with government run healthcare, politicians make YOUR healthcare decisions. THEY decide if you’ll get the procedure you need, or if you are disqualified because the treatment is too expensive or because you are too old. We can’t have that in America” (emphasis in original).24

Cost-control approaches that emphasize the need to ration and reduce consumption of medical care are politically vulnerable. Reformers can insist that they want to limit only inappropriate care in line with evidence-based medicine. The intent, in other words, is to rationalize medical care rather than to ration it. Opponents, however, will still deride any government policies to substantially change medical practice or reduce medical services as a “one-size-fits-all” bureaucratic nightmare that threatens the doctor-patient relationship.24
Previous SectionNext Section
Limiting Volume Versus Limiting Prices

If the choice, as Aaron and colleagues put it, were between paying “for all beneficial medical care whatever the cost” or rationing,25 then the public would indeed be an obstacle to cost control. Americans’ collective inability to accept rationing and say “no” to more medical care is, from this perspective, responsible for our failure to control spending.

Yet rationing services is not the only—or most effective—way to control spending.26 We noted earlier that greater use of medical services is not the primary explanation for the higher level of U.S. health care spending relative to other rich democracies. As Gerard Anderson and colleagues summarize, the major reason is “the prices, stupid!”12 An extensive analysis by the McKinsey Global Institute emphasized prices, administrative overhead, and excess capacity for some services, while concluding that competing explanations—such as that the U.S. population is particularly unhealthy or that Americans use many more medical services than other people do—do not hold water.10
How other nations achieve lower prices.

Other nations achieve lower prices by paying for health services through either a single-payer or coordinated, multi-payer systems that set or negotiate fees with all providers.11 Analysts who seek greater productivity in medical care should recognize that productivity can be increased simply by paying less per service.27 Other OECD health systems also spend much less on administration, both because insurance is simpler and because providers do not face the burden of dealing with myriad payers and payment rules.

Our excessive payment rates generate excessive supply of some equipment and thereby inefficient use. “U.S. costs in outpatient settings,” Paul Ginsburg explains, “are higher because of subscale operation of facilities. With prices very high, out-patient facilities in the United States can earn a profit despite underutilizing capacity.”28 Moreover, the Medicare Payment Advisory Commission (MedPAC) argues that high prices may explain, in part, recent growth in imaging services.29 In other words, given provider-induced demand, high prices can result in increased volume of services. Hence, the effect of high prices extends beyond the price per service.
Providers’ responses to price controls.

Some analysts may believe that price restraints are not effective because of providers’ behavioral responses. Doctors, for example, could raise the reported volume and intensity of services when their fees are reduced. There is good evidence that this happens for physician services. Nonetheless, the impact of such volume and intensity offsets is limited. The Congressional Budget Office (CBO) concludes that physicians’ responses to Medicare payment reductions offset only about 25 percent of the “reduction in spending that would otherwise occur.”30
Constrained prices and access to care.

Others, including the health care industry, will argue that constraining prices limits patients’ access to medical care. Doctors, for example, might refuse to take new Medicare patients if Medicare pays much less than private insurers do. A solution to this problem is to adopt all-payer rate regulation in which public and private insurers use standard fee schedules to pay hospitals, doctors, and other providers.31 Because all insurers are paying the same fees and prices are constrained across the board, all-payer systems eliminate the problem of price discrimination (as well as that of cost shifting).
Previous SectionNext Section
U.S. Experience With Price Restraints

The United States has extensive experience with price regulation. That Americans are ostensibly individualistic and suspicious of government power has not stopped U.S. policymakers from adopting policies that strengthen federal regulatory power over prices.
Medicare.

In the face of rising federal deficits, Medicare initiated new payment regulations during the 1980s.32 Since then, Medicare has relied on price restraints and (in the late 1990s) an antifraud campaign to successfully moderate its spending growth. Medicare has, during the past two decades, performed better than private insurers in controlling spending for similar benefits, perhaps because of its greater purchasing power.33
Managed care.

Private insurers, of course, also seek lower prices or “discounts.” Many providers are paid by private insurers on the basis of the Medicare fee schedule. Moreover, the success of managed care during the mid-1990s in restraining medical care spending was largely attributable to price restraints rather than care management.34 For example, analyzing data from Massachusetts, David Cutler and colleagues found, for example, that virtually all of the savings that managed care plans achieved for heart disease treatment, relative to indemnity insurance, came from price reductions.27 During this period, health maintenance organizations (HMOs) and other insurers leveraged “purchasing power to negotiate price discounts with providers” who believed they had to make contract concessions “to ensure they did not lose patients or revenue as beneficiaries moved into managed care.”35 Managed care declined (and cost trends reversed) largely because consolidation of providers made it more difficult for insurers to extract price concessions.34

The public backlash against managed care was not an objection to controlling prices. Rather, discontent was based on perceived restrictions on services, as well as real limits on choice of providers. Limiting patients’ choice of providers to obtain price concessions—through selective contracting—is a particularly American strategy. Single-payer and multipayer systems outside the United States commonly restrain prices through all-payer negotiation or government fee setting without restricting choice of providers.11
Previous SectionNext Section
Political Barriers To Cost Control

Experience in the United States and around the world demonstrates that price regulation is the key to controlling health care costs. And though many Americans fear rationing of medical services or limits on their choice of doctors, public opinion data suggest that the public is supportive of price regulation.

Why, then, hasn’t the United States adopted more effective, systemwide policies to regulate medical care prices? One answer lies in the political economy of health care. National health spending amounts to income for medical care providers, insurers, pharmaceutical companies, medical device manufacturers, and a host of health care–related industries that profit from the status quo. Efforts to control health care spending consequently threaten the medical care industry’s income and trigger fierce political resistance.1,36,37 The fragmented nature of U.S. political institutions gives these stakeholders numerous opportunities during the legislative process to block cost-control measures.38 Thus, both the Carter administration’s proposal to cap hospitals’ rate increases and the Clinton administration’s proposal to cap the growth of insurance premiums were defeated in Congress after predictably drawing the industry’s ire.

Yet we should not underestimate the effect of another aspect of U.S. health care politics: U.S. health policy analysts’ excessive preoccupation with excessive utilization. Vladeck suggests that the interest-group and policy-community explanations may complement each other because, “if we focus our discussions on utilization, we don’t talk directly about prices—or incomes—and thus won’t directly threaten existing structures of power and prestige within the health care system or the political system.”9

The failure to confront the issue of providers’ and insurers’ incomes head-on encourages the misleading view that the public is to blame for our spending predicament. That view is doubly wrong: it overlooks the importance of higher prices in explaining American levels of spending on medical care, and it ignores evidence that the American public supports regulatory controls on those prices. The focus on rationing makes public opinion seem like more of an obstacle than it really is by assuming away effective cost-control methods that are more popular.

The focus on utilization has taken new form in the current emphasis on improving “value,” ironically defined as anything other than paying less per service. Thus, the health policy community promotes initiatives, from disease management to pay-for-performance and health information technology, for which evidence of potential savings is extremely scant.30,36
Previous SectionNext Section
Political Feasibility

We have no illusions that adopting systemwide price regulation is politically easy. Most health reform plans under debate in 2009, with the exception of proposals to create a new public insurance option, embrace delivery system reforms and avoid explicit discussion of price regulation. Given the health care industry’s response to the Clinton administration’s proposed spending limits and the persistent stigma of “price controls,” that omission is politically understandable. Yet we believe that there is greater public support than many assume for regulatory strategies if they focus on prices and administration rather than on the current reframing of “managed care.”

If Congress enacts a health reform bill that greatly expands insurance coverage, then fiscal pressures could, as has happened in Medicare, lead federal officials to turn to regulation. Perhaps the health care industry’s promise to cut health care spending will enable policymakers to adopt systemwide spending-control measures with teeth—including price limits—if the industry does not live up to that pledge.

We are not claiming that regulation of prices will solve all health care cost problems. We do think that the evidence is overwhelming that payment rates are primary; that without good control of payment rates, spending control will fail; that the United States can do much better on limiting rates of payment; that systems that control spending better do so mainly by better control of payment rates and that is even true within American experience; and that payment rates are also a major factor in other sources of spending, such as excessive dissemination of equipment that can then lead to excessive volume.

In short, regulating prices is a good place to start rationalizing American health care spending.

Previous SectionNext Section
Footnotes

Jonathan Oberlander (oberland{at}med.unc.edu) is associate professor of social medicine and of health policy and management at the University of North Carolina–Chapel Hill and a visiting scholar at the Russell Sage Foundation. Joseph White is the Luxenberg Family Professor of Public Policy in the Center for Policy Studies, Case Western Reserve University, in Cleveland, Ohio.

Previous Section

NOTES

?
Evans, RG. Devil take the hindmost: private health insurance and the rising costs of American exceptionalism. In: Morone JA, Litman TJ, Robins LS, editors. Health politics and policy, 4th ed. Clifton Park (NY): Delmar Cengage Learning; 2008. p. 445–74.
?
Anderson GF, Frogner BK. Health spending in OECD countries: obtaining value per dollar. Health Aff (Millwood). 2008;27(6):1718–27.
Abstract/FREE Full Text
?
Milstein A, Hoverman Colla C. Tracking the contribution of US health care to the global competitiveness of American employers and workers: 2009 Business Roundtable health care value comparability study [Internet]. San Francisco: Mercer; 2009 Feb 28 [cited 2009 Jun 17]. Available from: http://us.select.mercer.com/ps/81724/p/21/blurb/145847/article/20096311/
?
Samuelson R. Obama’s health-care headache. Washington Post. 2009 Jan 12; A13.
?
Neumann PJ. Using cost-effectiveness analysis to improve medical care: opportunities and barriers. New York (NY): Oxford University Press; 2007. p. 57.
?
Aaron HJ, Schwartz WB. The painful prescription: rationing hospital care. Washington (DC): Brookings Institution; 1984.
?
Jost TS. Health care at risk: a critique of the consumer-driven movement. Durham (NC): Duke University Press; 2007.
?
President’s Advisory Panel on Federal Tax Reform. Simple, fair, and pro-growth: proposals to fix America’s tax system. Washington (DC): U.S. Government Printing Office; 2005. p. 80–1.
?
Vladeck BC. Everything new is old again. Health Aff (Millwood). 2004;23:VAR-111.
?
Angrisano C, Farrell D, Kocher B, Laboissiere M, Parker S. Accounting for the cost of health care in the United States [Internet]. San Francisco (CA): McKinsey Global Institute; 2007 Jan [cited 2009 Jun 17]. Available from: http://www.mckinsey.com/mgi/rp/healthcare/accounting_cost_healthcare.asp
?
White J. Competing solutions: American health care proposals and international experience. Washington (DC): Brookings Institution; 1995.
?
Anderson GF, Reinhardt UE, Hussey PS, Petrosyan V. It’s the prices, stupid: why the United States is so different from other countries. Health Aff (Millwood). 2003;22(3):89–105.
Abstract/FREE Full Text
?
Anderson GF, Hussey PS, Frogner BK, Waters HR. Health spending in the United States and the rest of the industrialized world. Health Aff (Millwood) 2005;24(4) 03–14.
Abstract/FREE Full Text
?
Altman D. Pulling it together: the ‘r’ word is back [Internet]. Menlo Park (CA): Kaiser Family Foundation; 2008 Sep 12 [cited 2009 Aug 3]. Available from: http://www.kff.org/pullingittogether/120908_altman.cfm
?
Schlesinger M, Lee T. Is health care different? Popular support of federal health and social policies. J Health Polit Polic. 1993;18(3 Pt 2):551–628.
CrossRef
?
Shapiro RY, Young JY. The polls: medical care in the United States. Public Opin Quart. 1986;50(3):418–28.
Abstract/FREE Full Text
?
Kaiser Family Foundation/Harvard School of Public Health. Toplines: the public’s health care agenda for the new president and Congress [Internet]. Menlo Park (CA): Kaiser Family Foundation; 2009 Jan 15 [cited 2009 Jun 17]. Available from: http://kff.org/kaiserpolls/7853.cfm
?
ABC News/Kaiser Family Foundation/USA Today. Health care in America 2006 survey [Internet]. Menlo Park (CA): Kaiser Family Foundation; 2006 Oct [cited 2009 Jun 17]. Available from: http://www.kff.org/kaiserpolls/upload/7572.pdf
?
Kim M, Blendon RJ, Benson JM. How interested are Americans in new medical technologies? A multinational comparison. Health Aff (Millwood). 2001;20(5):194–201.
FREE Full Text
?
Jacobs LR. 1994 all over again? Public opinion and health care. N Engl J Med. 2008;358(18):1881–3.
CrossRefMedline
?
Schlesinger M. Reprivatizing the public household? Medical care in the context of American public values. J Health Polit Polic. 2004;29(4–5) 69–1004.
CrossRef
?
McCaughey B. Ruin your health with the Obama stimulus plan: Betsy McCaughey [Internet]. Bloomberg News Service. 2009 Feb 9 [cited 2009 Jun 17]. Available from: http://www.bloomberg.com/apps/news?pid=20601039&refer=columnist_mccaughey&sid=aLzfDxfbwhzs
?
House Republican Conference. Question and answer: government-rationed health care. Washington (DC): House Republican Conference; 2009 Feb 10 [cited 2009 Jun 17]. Available from: http://www.gop.gov/policy-news/09/02/10/question-and-answer-government-rationed
?
Luntz FI. The language of healthcare 2009 [Internet]. Alexandria (VA): Luntz, Maslansky Strategic Research; 2009 May [cited 2009 Jun 17]. Available from: http://www.politico.com/static/PPM116_luntz.html
?
Aaron HJ, Schwartz WB, with Cox M. Can we say no? The challenge of rationing health care. Washington (DC): Brookings Institution; 2005. p. 148.
?
Marmor TR, Klein R. Cost vs. care: America’s health care dilemma wrongly considered. Health Matrix. 1986;4(1):19–24.
Medline
?
Cutler DM, McClellan M, Newhouse JP. How does managed care do it? RAND J Econ. 2000;31:526–48.
CrossRefMedline
?
Ginsburg PB. High and rising health care costs: demystifying U.S. health care spending [Internet]. Princeton (NJ): Robert Wood Johnson Foundation; 2008 Oct [cited 2009 Jun 17]. Research Synthesis Report. p. 10. Available from: http://www.rwjf.org/files/research/101508.policysynthesis.costdrivers.rpt.pdf
?
Hackbarth GM. Report to the Congress: Medicare payment policy, statement before the Subcommittee on Health, Committee on Ways and Means, U.S. House of Representatives [Internet]. Washington (DC): Medicare Payment Advisory Commission; 2009 Mar 17 [cited 2009 Jun 17]. Available from: http://www.medpac.gov/documents/Mar09_March%20report%20testimony_WM%20FINAL.pdf
?
Congressional Budget Office. Key issues in analyzing major health insurance proposals. Washington (DC): CBO; 2008.
?
White J. Cost control and health care reform: the case for all-payer regulation. Washington (DC): Campaign for America’s Future; 2009. Available from: http://www.ourfuture.org/healthcare/white
?
Oberlander J. The political life of Medicare. Chicago (IL): University of Chicago Press; 2003.
?
Medicare Payment Advisory Commission. Healthcare spending and the Medicare program. Washington (DC): MedPAC; 2008 Jun. p. 9.
?
White J. Markets and medical care: the United States, 1993–2005. Milbank Q. 2007;85(3):395–448.
CrossRefMedline
?
Grossman J, Strunk FC, Hurley RE. Reversal of fortune: Medicare+Choice collides with market forces [Internet]. Washington (DC): Center for Studying Health System Change; 2002 May [cited 2009 Jun 19]. Issue Brief no. 52. p. 1–4. Available from: http://www.hschange.org/CONTENT/437/437.pdf
?
Marmor T, Oberlander J, White J. The Obama administration’s options for health care cost control: hope versus reality. Ann Intern Med. 2009;150(7):485–9.
CrossRefMedline
?
Marmor TR. Political analysis and American medical care. New York (NY): Cambridge University Press; 1983.
?
Morone JA. The bias of American politics: rationing health care in a weak state. U Pa L Rev 1992;150:1923–38.

« Previous | Next Article » Table of Contents
This Article

doi: 10.1377/hlthaff.28.5.1285 Health Aff September/October 2009 vol. 28 no. 5 1285-1293

AbstractFree
» Full Text
PDF

Classifications

Overview

Services

Email this article to a colleague
Alert me when this article is cited
Alert me if a correction is posted
Alert me when new responses are published
Article Usage Statistics
Similar articles in this journal
Similar articles in Web of Science
Similar articles in PubMed
Add to My Personal Archive
Download to citation manager
Request Permissions

Responses

Submit a response
No responses published

Citing Articles

Load citing article information
Citing articles via Web of Science
Citing articles via Google Scholar

Google Scholar

Articles by Oberlander, J.
Articles by White, J.
Search for related content

PubMed

PubMed citation
Articles by Oberlander, J.
Articles by White, J.

Related Content

Health Reform
Public Opinion
Health Spending
Consumer Issues
Load related web page information

Navigate This Article

Top
Abstract
The Public And Cost Control
Limits Of Public Opinion
Limiting Volume Versus Limiting Prices
U.S. Experience With Price Restraints
Political Barriers To Cost Control
Political Feasibility
Footnotes
NOTES

 

Human101948

(3,457 posts)
6. Very informative...but an excerpt would be sufficient...
Fri Apr 1, 2016, 10:43 AM
Apr 2016

I just couldn't get through the footnotes.

DhhD

(4,695 posts)
11. Another side of the issue.
Fri Apr 1, 2016, 01:04 PM
Apr 2016

ACA Silver PLan: 3 doctor visits, $170.00 first visit. Then doctor says since you have 3 visits, I will not give the customary 2 - 90 days supply of Hypertension generic prescription; you can just come back in 3 months. The patient will need 5 months to pay off that first visit before having the lab work done that is supposed to cost a $20 co-pay. So at month six, the patient will need to pay $220 for basic lab work, check blood sugar, cholesterol, and thyroid hormone level. Then there is the upcoming $20 copay for all the specialist visits that are set up on a 6 month referral. However the patient's cloudy yellow growth on the eyeball and sometimes cloudy vision is taken care of by the doctor's verbal recommendation to see a Optometrist for a pressure check. The Silver Plan has a premium for this patient each month. So by the time the patient is able to see the specialist it is time to see the doctor for that last, and third time, for a prescription for a $5 card of Lisinopril for Hypertension. By then it is time for the 2017 ACA application renewal. The patient has paid for the Silver Plan but got Bronze care. The government has paid the Insurance Company, that holds the Silver Plan, a large subsidy for Bronze care. That same Silver Plan is going up in price. Care for Americans is becoming Bronze Plans as prices rise each year. We needed a Public Option Plan for those age 56 and over. Medicare is very expensive too.

Baobab, to me your reply is about younger healthy Americans, not those who are needing a lot of healthcare procedures or healthcare that is age related. Americans for the most part are not as healthy as they could be if we were receiving universal healthcare back in the late 1980's as Jesse Jackson proposed in 1988. Jackson and Sanders are on the same page in my opinion. Thanks for your reply.

Baobab

(4,667 posts)
12. Both Obama and Clinton were/are limited by trade policy
Fri Apr 1, 2016, 01:14 PM
Apr 2016

Health care policy is poisoned by trade policy. This is not commonly known.

Baobab

(4,667 posts)
13. Healthcare (and all public services) have to be COMPLETELY free to be "FTA-legal"
Fri Apr 1, 2016, 01:25 PM
Apr 2016

See the discussion on the reasons for this here.

Baobab

(4,667 posts)
8. The main point I wanted to make is that we've been misled about why
Fri Apr 1, 2016, 11:06 AM
Apr 2016

health care is so screwed up.

We've been lied to about a lot of things - Things like Americans get too much care or that competition lowers prices in for profit health care are clearly misrepresentations. (health care is different than the usual situation- competition actually makes it more expensive)

We should realize we've spent the last decade being told a lot of misinformation.And starting in 2007 the misinformation level skyrocketed.

If Bernie wins we will see that a lot of what we've been told about healthcare especially, but also about a lot of other things are wrong. We have a lot of ways we can save money. We dont have to globalize and subcontract. We just need single payer. We need a professionally implemented single payer system. (Single payer means NO INSURANCE COMPANIES, in other words, no "gap" insurances, because there is no gap.)

Got it? if the current insurance system remains it cannot be free to the end user, it cannot simplify, it has to coddle them and it cant save money. then everything breaks. There is no "public option" everybody is in, nobody is out and thats not optional.

Our current system is really screwed up. A lot of people have died because they were denied health care unnecessarily. They knew that it could not work.

 

Old Codger

(4,205 posts)
9. Costs more and people are sicker
Fri Apr 1, 2016, 11:34 AM
Apr 2016

when they finally go in just because it costs too much to start with, office visit can run upwards of $100 or more and if tests are needed, and usually are, it gets really up there.. Unless you have a decent insurance or a lot of money you don;t go in til it gets pretty bad.. so you are sicker and takes more care to get past it

Baobab

(4,667 posts)
10. Insurance companies deliberately dump sick people with huge sudden bills
Fri Apr 1, 2016, 12:12 PM
Apr 2016

Americans are not sicker than other countries, nor do we use more health care, we actually use less. Because insurance companies have doctors sign contracts which force them not just to deny care, also prohibit them from even talking about other options for diagnosis and treatment.

There is no way to make the insurance system work, they are way better at the game of dumping people than we could ever be at preventing it.

Globalizing will make it even worse because foreign doctors and nurses will have even less freedom to be honest. With their presence here in the country dependent on their employers whims.

Important: Most Americans think insurers pay a much larger share of costs than they actually do.

They successfully dump 64% of the costs onto the government. See the link I posted recently to the paper on this.

So we are likely already paying enough in taxes for quality, free national health care and not getting it.

Latest Discussions»Retired Forums»Bernie Sanders»bernie appears to me to b...